This Week
  • HBT Architects took a risk and parted with some clients on its new path.

  • East High School teacher and blogger Kelly LaLonde speaks out about education.

  • GM injection: The automaker has invested $150 million here since 2011.

  • Placing a loved one in an elder care facility is not an easy decision for caregivers.

  • Robert W. Hurlbut heads a 1,400-employee business started by his grandparents.

  • The new edition of Explore Greater Rochester is here.

Society and the economy need a strong cultural foundation

Click to enlarge
By KENT GARDNER
Policy Wonk
Rochester Business Journal
January 17, 2014

Few of us make decisions based on a purely rational assessment of our own self-interest. And thank goodness for that! Life with homo economicus, “economic man,” would be dreary indeed.

There is a deep tradition in economics that considers the role that “institutions”—defined here as traditions, cultural mores and social organizations—play in society. A cultural value of honesty, for example, contributes to a more efficient economy. Traditions and cultural norms, even without any claim to morality, also bring societal benefit. Laws and explicit rules cannot create a good society unless they are built upon a strong cultural foundation. I illustrate this below in three spheres: the macroeconomy, government and the firm.

Consider national tax compliance. Americans cheat on their taxes less than citizens of other nations—much less, in some instances. The Internal Revenue Service estimates that 83 percent of taxes owed were paid, and paid on time, in 2012. Contrast that record with Greece, where tax evasion has been called the national pastime: On average, the Greeks pay only two-thirds of what they should. And it isn’t because we hire more tax police. Greece spends four times as much per capita chasing tax cheats. Historically, the Russians have been even worse: Income tax compliance has been at 50 percent.

Without a strong tradition of voluntary compliance, the central government spends more on enforcement and must rely on forms of taxation that are more easily enforced but may be less equitable and, in economic terms, create more inefficiency.

“What about ‘The Wolf of Wall Street’ and the self-dealing that contributed to the financial crisis?” I’m not making a global claim to the moral superiority of the average American. Special interests have successfully lobbied for the insertion of custom tax provisions that make evasion, for some, entirely legal. Transparency International’s Corruption Perception Index places the United States at No. 19 of 177 countries—not terrible, but not at the top with the Scandinavians and New Zealand. We have a strong compliance culture around taxes, but we fall short in countless other spheres.

Culture and tradition also play an important role in the political sphere. This week the U.S. Supreme Court heard arguments in National Labor Relations Board v. Noel Canning. This is part of the long-running Washington soap opera about presidential appointments; minority Republicans using the filibuster and other tactics have inhibited Senate consideration of appointments by the Obama White House. Exasperated, the president made a few “recess” appointments—which persist until the next session of Congress—when the Senate was out of town, asserting that the Senate was not simply absent but in recess. As the Senate was convening pro forma sessions every three days (presumably at the direction of the majority leader, Democrat Harry Reid), Senate Republicans argue that it was not in recess and the appointments were therefore unconstitutional.

And we also witnessed the demise of the Senate’s longstanding filibuster rule. Silly rule, really: A senator could delay proceedings as long as he or she could keep talking. As senators are nothing if not long-winded, talking ad nauseum comes naturally. Only a vote of three-fifths of the Senate could halt a filibuster. The minority party thus needs only 41 seats to threaten the majority with a costly and embarrassing filibuster. So Reid and the Democrats changed how the rule can be used.

Culture and tradition matter. The Senate’s responsibility to consider presidential appointments in a timely fashion—and typically confirm the nominees—reflects deference to the office of president, regardless of party. The Senate can and should refuse to confirm some appointments, thus nudging the president toward whatever consensus rules in that chamber. But generally the Senate plays nice and the president, for his part, doesn’t abuse the power to make recess appointments, even when the fact of the recess is unambiguous. Deference to tradition would make it unnecessary to rigidly define “recess” or remove the president’s power to act when a recess occurs.

The same principle applies to the filibuster. It may seem to be a silly tradition, but it served as an escape valve when a member of the Senate felt deeply and wanted to make a dramatic statement. The chamber would be nearly empty; the senator was welcome to talk, but other senators didn’t have to listen. And eventually the drama would end and business would resume. Using the filibuster (or threat of one) as a standard operating procedure, however, violated the cultural norm. Deference to tradition allows this “escape valve” to remain in existence, a subtle component of the balance of power among the members and between the political parties.

Culture plays a role in the workplace, too. When I arrived at the Center for Governmental Research after having been a SUNY college faculty member, I asked about the travel policy. “Be reasonable,” I was told.

Reasonable?! Where’s the list of allowable lodging expenses by city? What’s the maximum reimbursement for dinner? A glass of wine is on your own tab, right?

At CGR, we pride ourselves on having fewer rules than large organizations—because we have a culture that respects our mission and engenders mutual respect among the staff. On the rare occasion when this trust is abused, it is apparent to all—and this reinforces the value we all receive from working in an atmosphere of trust and respect.

Culture is the foundation of a good society—and, surprisingly, of a competitive economy. We can’t pass enough laws or hire enough cops to overcome consistently self-interested behavior. Preserving a moral code is the job of families, schools, the faith community—even the workplace. A market-based economy can harness our competitive and selfish reflexes to better ends: Markets, like laws, can help protect the community from individual greed. Yet economies can’t survive without a culture that reinforces trust and honorable behavior. No society prospers on self-interest that is limited only by markets or the rule of law.

Kent Gardner is chief economist and chief research officer of the Center for Governmental Research Inc.

1/17/14 (c) 2014 Rochester Business Journal. To obtain permission to reprint this article, call 585-546-8303 or email service@rbj.net.


What You're Saying 

There are no comments yet. Be the first to add yours!

Post Your Own Comment

 
Username:
Password:

Not registered? Sign up now!
 

To Do   Text Size
Post CommentPost A Comment eMail Size1
View CommentsView All Comments PrintPrint Size2
ReprintsReprints Size3
  • E-mailed
  • Commented
  • Viewed
RBJ   Google